Acta Universitatis Danubius. Œconomica, Vol 10, No 6 (2014)
A Study of Cobb-Douglas
Production Function with Differential Geometry
Alin Cristian Ioan1
Abstract: In this paper we shall made an analysis of Cobb-Douglas production function from the differential point of view. We shall obtain some interesting results about the nature of the points of the surface, the total curvature, the conditions when a production function is minimal and finally we give the equations of the geodesics on the surface i.e. the curves of minimal length between two points.
Keywords: production functions; metric; curvature; geodesic; Cobb-Douglas
JEL Classification: E23
1. Introduction
In the theory of production functions, all computations and phenomenons are studied for a constant level of production. In order to detect many aspects of them, a complete analysis can be made only at the entire surface.
We therefore define on R2 – the production space for two resources: K – capital and L - labor as SP=(K,L)K,L0 where xSP, x=(K,L) is an ordered set of resources. Because in a production process, depending on the nature of applied technology, but also its specificity, not any amount of resources are possible, we restrict the production area to a subset DpSP called domain of production.
It is called a Cobb-Douglas production function an application:
Q:DpR+, (K,L)Q(K,L)=cKLR+ (K,L)Dp, ,R*+, c0
The production function is C-differentiable and homogenous of degree +.
2. The Differential Geometry of Cobb-Douglas Surface
The graph representation of a production function is a surface.
Let note in what follows:
(1) p= , q= , r= , s= , t=
We have after simple calculations:
(2) p= , q= , r= , s= , t=
The bordered Hessian:
(3) Hf= =
therefore, because:
(4) B1= = 0, B2= = 0
we obtain that Q is quasiconcave, that is for any aR, Q-1([a,)) is convex in R2.
For a constant value of one parameter we obtain a curve on the surface, that is Q=Q(K,L0) or Q=Q(K0,L) are both curves on the production surface. They are obtained from the intersection of the plane L=L0 or K=K0 with the surface Q=Q(K,L).
In the study of the surfaces, two quadratic forms are very useful.
The first fundamental quadratic form of the surface is:
(5) g=g11dL2+2g12dLdK+g22dK2
where: g11=1+p2, g12=pq, g22=1+q2.
In our case:
(6) g11= , g12= , g22=
The area element is:
(7) d= dKdL= dKdL=
and the surface area A when (K,L)R (a region in the plane K-O-L) is A= .
The second fundamental form of the surface is:
(8) h=h11dL2+2 h12dLdK+ h22dK2
where: h11= , h12= , h22= .
In our case:
(9) h11= , h12= ,
h22=
Considering the quantity =h11h22-h122 we have that:
(10) =
If >0 in each point of the surface, we will say that it is elliptical. Such surfaces are the hyperboloid with two sheets, the elliptical paraboloid and the ellipsoid.
If 0 in each point of the surface, we will say that it is hyperbolic. Such surfaces are the hyperboloid with one sheet and the hyperbolic paraboloid.
If =0 in each point of the surface, we will say that it is parabolic. Such surfaces are the cone surfaces and the cylinder surfaces.
From (10) we find that:
: the production surface is elliptical;
: the production surface is parabolic;
: the production surface is hyperbolic
The curvature of a curve is, from an elementary point of view, the degree of deviation of the curve relative to a straight line. Considering a surface S and an arbitrary curve through a point P of the surface who has the tangent vector v in P, let the plane determined by the vector v and the normal N in P at S. The intersection of with S is a curve Cn named normal section of S. Its curvature is called normal curvature.
If we have a direction m= in the tangent plane of the surface in an arbitrary point P we have that the normal curvature is given by:
(11) k(m)=
The extreme values k1 and k2 of the function k(m) are called the principal curvatures of the surface in that point. They satisfy also the equation:
(12) (g11g22-g122)k2-(g11h22-2g12h12+g22h11)k+(h11h22-h122)=0
The values of m, who give the extremes, call principal directions in that point.
They also satisfy the equation:
(13) (g11s-g12r)m2+(g11t-g22r)m+(g12t-g22s)=0
The curve =m (where m is one of the principal directions) is called line of curvature on the surface. On such a curve we have the maximum or minimum variation of the value of Q in a neighborhood of P.
The quantity K=k1k2 is named the total curvature in the considered point and H= is named the mean curvature of the surface in that point.
We have therefore:
(14) K= = =
(15) H= =
A surface with K=constant call surface with constant total curvature and if H=0 call minimal surface. In our case we can see that K=0 if and only if: +=1.
If we consider now in the tangent plane at the surface in a point P a direction m, if h11m2+2 h12m+h22=0 we will say that m is an asymptotic direction, and the equation: gives the asymptotic curves of the surface in the point P.
In our case, the asymptotic directions are:
(16) m1= , m2=
If +=1 then both asymptotic directions are equal.
With notations x1=L, x2=K, let define now the Christoffel symbols of first order:
(17) ij,k=
and of second order:
(18) =gi1jk,1+gi2jk,2
where g11= G, g12=- F, g22= E are the components of the inverse matrix of .
We have now:
(19) 11,1= , 11,2= , 12,1= , 12,2= ,
22,1= , 22,2=
(20) =g1111,1+g1211,2= ,
=g2111,1+g2211,2= ,
=g1112,1+g1212,2= ,
=g2112,1+g2212,2= ,
=g1122,1+g1222,2= ,
=g2122,1+g2222,2=
From the upper we find that:
(21) 11,1= , 11,2= ,
12,1= , 12,2= ,
22,1= , 22,2=
(22) = ,
= ,
= ,
= ,
= ,
=
A geodesic is in common language the shortest curve between two points. It is useful when we try to determine the shortest way to go from a production at other in a minimum time. The equation of a geodesic is:
(23)
that is:
(24)
(25)
or, with the quantities determined:
(24)
(25)
The equations of geodesics are: L=L(s), K=K(s) where s is the element of arc on the curves.
3. References
Arrow, K.J., Chenery, H.B., Minhas, B.S. & Solow, R.M. (1961). Capital Labour Substitution and Economic Efficiency. Review of Econ and Statistics, 63, pp. 225-250.
Cobb, C.W. & Douglas, P.H. (1928). A Theory of Production. American Economic Review, 18, pp. 139–165.
Ioan, C.A. (2007). Applications of the space differential geometry at the study of production functions. Euroeconomica, 18, pp. 30-38.
Ioan, C.A. (2004). Applications of geometry at the study of production functions. The Annals of Danubius University, Fascicle I, Economics, pp. 27-39.
Kadiyala, K.R. (1972). Production Functions and Elasticity of Substitution. Southern Economic Journal, 38(3), pp. 281-284.
Kmenta, J. (1967). On Estimation of the CES Production Function. International Economic Review, 8(2), pp. 180-189.
Liu, T.C. & Hildebrand, G.H. (1965). Manufacturing Production Functions in the United States, 1957. Ithaca: Cornell Univ. Press.
Mishra, S.K. (2007). A Brief History of Production Functions. Shillong, India: North-Eastern Hill University.
Revankar, N.S. (1971). A Class of Variable Elasticity of Substitution Production Functions. Econometrica, 39(1), pp. 61-71.
Sato, R. (1974). On the Class of Separable Non-Homothetic CES Functions. Economic Studies Quarterly, 15, pp. 42-55.
1 Nicolae Oncescu College, Romania, Address: 1-3 Şos. Brăilei, Ianca, Braila County, Romania, Tel.: +40239668494, Corresponding author: alincristianioan@yahoo.com.
AUDŒ, Vol. 10, no. 6, pp. 67-74
Refbacks
- There are currently no refbacks.
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.